Abstract
To estimate the emissions reductions and costs of a climate policy, analysts usually compare a policy scenario with a baseline scenario of future economic conditions without the policy. Both scenarios require assumptions about the future course of numerous factors such as population growth, technical change, and non-climate policies like taxes. The results are only reliable to the extent that the future turns out to be reasonably close to the assumptions that went into the model.
In this paper we examine the effects of unanticipated macroeconomic shocks to growth in developing countries or a global financial crisis on the performance of three climate policy regimes: a globally-harmonized carbon tax; a global cap and trade system; and the McKibbin-Wilcoxen hybrid. We use the G-Cubed dynamic general equilibrium model to explore how the shocks would affect emissions, prices, incomes, and wealth under each regime. We consider how the different climate policies tend to increase or decrease the shock's effect in the global economy and draw inferences about which policy approaches might better withstand such shocks.
We find that a global cap and trade regime significantly changes the way growth shocks would otherwise be transmitted between regions while price-based systems such as a global carbon tax or a hybrid policy do not. Moreover, in the case of a financial meltdown, a price based system enables significant emissions reductions at low economic cost whereas a quantity target base system loses the opportunity for low cost emission reduction reductions because the target is fixed.
Summary for Policymakers
Overview
Because any effective international climate policy will need to be in place for centuries, many unexpected macroeconomic shocks will occur during the policy's existence. This paper explores how such shocks affect global economic conditions under three different international climate policies: a cap-and-trade system, a harmonized carbon tax, and a hybrid policy. The results show that in many respects, carbon tax and hybrid policies are more resilient than a cap-and-trade system.
Discussion
The global financial crisis, a looming global recession, and turmoil in credit markets drive home the importance of developing a global climate architecture that can withstand major economic disruptions. Such an architecture needs to be resilient to large and unexpected changes in economic growth, technology, energy prices, demographic trends, and other factors that affect the costs of emissions abatement. The stability of global policy has important environmental implications for two reasons.
First, collapse of the policy could set back progress on emissions reductions for years. Second, since the decisions of economic actors depend on their expectations of future policy, policies that are vulnerable to shocks are less likely to encourage long-term investments in new technologies and emissions reductions.
This paper uses a computational macroeconomic model to explore how shocks in the global economy propagate under three different climate policy regimes: a cap-and-trade system, a globally-harmonized carbon tax, and a hybrid system of national long-term permit trading. The paper examines two kinds of shocks relevant to recent experience: (1) a positive shock to economic growth in China, India, and other developing countries, and (2) a sharp decline in housing markets and a rise in
global equity risk premiums, causing severe financial distress in the global economy. The paper compares economic results under the three climate regimes in the decade following the shock and draws inferences about which regimes offer the strongest incentives to sustain participation in the climate agreement.
The results show that although these three climate regimes appear to be similar in their ability to reduce carbon emissions efficiently, they differ in how they affect the transmission of economic disturbances between economies. These differences have important implications for the political robustness of these policies.
Key Findings and Recommendations
- All else equal, a climate regime that exacerbates downward macroeconomic shocks or depresses the benefits of positive macroeconomic shocks would be more costly and less stable than a system that better handles global business cycles and other volatility. This occurs because macroeconomic shocks can cause the cost of regulation to be much higher or lower than anticipated. These economic surprises can subject governments to enormous pressures to relax or repeal taxes or other policies perceived to impede economic growth.
- Any policy framework whose costs or benefits depend strongly on forecasts of the future state of the world or national economic conditions is likely to fail, because the forecast is likely to be wrong. Countries committing to targets and timetables for emissions reductions are committing to a policy with highly uncertain costs. A global climate framework needs to endure even in the face of the wide variety of shocks that will undoubtedly occur over the coming decades. Thus, there must be a mechanism built into the framework that directly addresses the issue of cost uncertainty.
- It is critical to get the global and national governance structures right. There must be a clear regulatory regime in each country and a transparent way to smooth out excessive short-term volatility in prices. A system that enables or even encourages short-term financial speculation in climate markets may collapse at huge expense to national economies. A hybrid system provides many of the advantages of a permit system while limiting opportunities for speculation through the annual permit mechanism.
- Since shocks in one part of the world will certainly occur, the global system needs to have adequate firewalls between national climate systems to prevent destructive contagion from propagating local problems into a system-wide failure. A global cap-andtrade system would be extremely vulnerable to shocks in any single economy. A system based on national hybrid policies, on the other hand, would be explicitly designed to partition national climate markets and limit the effects of a collapse in climate policy in one part of the world on climate markets elsewhere.
- In many respects, a global cap-and-trade system is less robust to macroeconomic shocks than a carbon tax or hybrid system. A global cap-and-trade system can cause unexpectedly high growth in one country to reduce growth in other economies. Carbon taxes and hybrid policies are not vulnerable to this effect. Additionally, if a global financial crisis were to occur, a cap-and-trade system would miss the opportunity for significant additional low-cost emissions reductions.
Conclusion
The global financial crisis of 2008 has starkly emphasized a number of important lessons for the design of global and national climate policy. These lessons need to be considered explicitly during international negotiations for future climate agreement. Anticipating shocks may mean rejecting global climate policies that reduce emissions reliably in stable economic conditions but are vulnerable to collapse in volatile conditions.
McKibbin, Warwick, Adele Morris and Peter Wilcoxen. “Expecting the Unexpected: Macroeconomic Volatility and Climate Policy.” Harvard Project on Climate Agreements, November 2008