Abstract
We recommend that the successor to the Kyoto Protocol (“Kyoto II”) impose mandatory ceilings on rich countries’ greenhouse gas emissions and that it promote the participation of developing countries. Our proposal requires two major changes to the current Protocol, the use of an escape clause and the potential use of trade restrictions. The agreement must be seen as fair to developing nations. These countries will be subject to disciplines that prevent them from undermining the agreement in the short run, and they will be required to accept the principle that they will have to reduce emissions in the longer run. International trade in emissions permits plays a modest role in our proposal. The agreement should not attempt to prescribe the national policies (e.g. cap and trade or taxes or a hybrid) used to achieve reductions.
The escape clause gives signatories the option to reduce their abatement, provided that they pay a penalty. We discuss two mechanisms for imposing this penalty, either a monetary fine or WTO-sanctioned trade restrictions. The escape clause option is similar to the often-discussed “safety valve”, in that it puts a ceiling on actual abatement costs, thereby reducing the expected costs and the risk of membership. The escape clause proposal also helps to solve the problem of inducing nations to join the agreement and of inducing members to comply with their commitments. The severity of the (implicit or explicit) fine increases with the number of members. Therefore, a potential member’s decision to join the agreement increases other members’ incentive to abate. This added leverage promotes membership, helping to solve the participation problem. The absence of institutions that compel signatories to carry out their commitments has weakened the Kyoto Protocol. Our escape clause proposal addresses the enforcement problem by transforming an exotic commitment (reduction of emissions) into a familiar requirement (payment of an international financial obligation or adherence to a trade commitment). Institutions currently exist to help enforce these kinds of international commitments.
Developing nations are not required to reduce emissions in Kyoto II, which should be in force for no more than a decade. However, in order to be eligible to participate in the Clean Development Mechanism, developing nations are subject to trade disciplines that prevent them from undercutting signatories’ emissions reductions. Within developed countries, potential “carbon leakage” is either perceived as a problem or is used as an excuse for inaction. Kyoto II should allow nations incurring abatement costs to make border tax adjustments in order to minimize carbon leakage. We think that carefully designed trade disciplines can reduce the danger of leakage, removing it as a political obstacle, without undermining the current trade regime. We also see trade restrictions playing a role in pressuring developing nations to commit in principle to reducing emissions at a future round of negotiations, following Kyoto II.
SUMMARY FOR POLICYMAKERS
OVERVIEW
This paper proposes a design for a post-2012 international climate agreement (Kyoto II) to follow the Kyoto Protocol. The proposed design would impose national limits on rich countries' greenhouse gas emissions and promote voluntary abatement by developing countries. It includes two new features aimed at promoting participation and compliance and addressing concerns about carbon leakage: (1) an escape clause that would give signatories the option to reduce their abatement requirements in exchange for a penalty and (2) the use of trade restrictions.
DISCUSSION
The primary objective in designing a successor agreement to the Kyoto Protocol is to promote participation and compliance. Other design details are irrelevant if nations do not sign the treaty, or if they sign it but do not honor their commitments. Given limited ability to compel the behavior of sovereign nations, an agreement must be designed so that it is in individual countries' interest to participate and comply. A new agreement should also set the stage for increased commitment and greater developing-country participation in the future.
Overall, the proposed design for Kyoto II shares many features of the current Kyoto Protocol: it would impose mandatory emissions ceilings on rich countries and preserve existing mechanisms for promoting voluntary abatement efforts in developing countries, including Joint Implementation (JI) and the Clean Development Mechanism (CDM). Nations would be free to choose whatever combination of domestic policies (cap-and-trade, carbon taxes, JI, and CDM, etc.) they prefer to achieve compliance. Developing countries would not face mandatory abatement commitments for the relatively short (at most tenyear) period covered by Kyoto II. But to avail themselves of the benefits of participation, they would need to accept the concept of future obligations in principle. Other key elements of the proposed design—including new mechanisms to address cost and leakage concerns—are summarized below.
KEY FINDINGS & RECOMMENDATIONS
- Mandatory emission ceilings: As already noted, rich countries would accept mandatory ceilings under the new agreement. Developing countries would not be subject to abatement requirements, but would be put on notice that they will face obligations in the next round of negotiations. The treaty would encourage voluntary steps and agreements among parties outside Kyoto II while recognizing that these are not substitutes for a multi-national agreement with mandatory reduction commitments.
- ➢ Short duration: A Kyoto II agreement should cover eight to ten years and no more. A relatively short-lived agreement helps account for uncertainty and new information and makes it easier to incorporate changing responsibilities between developed and developing countries.
- Escape clause: Nations with mandatory emissions ceilings would have the option to reduce their abatement commitment in exchange for either paying a monetary fine or accepting trade sanctions imposed by other signatory nations. By providing protection against unexpectedly high abatement costs, this mechanism reduces barriers to participation while simultaneously creating incentives for compliance. The severity of the penalty (whether in the form of a fine or trade sanctions) would increase as more nations join, thereby further leveraging incentives for membership and compliance.
- Trade measures: In addition to the potential use of trade sanctions in the context of an escape clause, Kyoto II should recognize the use of trade reform in achieving climate-related objectives. Specifically, the authors support the use of carefully circumscribed border tax adjustments to protect against leakage (leakage is a shorthand term for the possibility that firms will simply re-locate to nations without mandatory commitments to escape carbon costs, thereby undermining the environmental objective and raising competitiveness concerns in signatory nations). Thoughtfully applied, such a policy can create effective incentives for countries to participate rather than staying outside the agreement.
- Tradable emissions: Kyoto II should allow international trade in emissions permits. While acknowledging that such trade could marginally reduce incentives to join or levels of abatement undertaken, the authors conclude that the potential for perverse effects is outweighed by the efficiency gains achievable through trade in the context of varying abatement costs. Permit trading or allocation should not, however, play an important role in creating inducements for participation. Instead, JI and CDM should be the primary mechanisms used to encourage membership and capture low-cost abatement opportunities.
CONCLUSION
This proposal builds on the existing Kyoto Protocol but introduces two major new features to address problems of participation and compliance. The inclusion of an escape clause will make it easier for nations to join, helps solve the enforcement problem, and serves to cap costs. The use of trade policy to address leakage concerns and strengthen incentives for participation is likely to be viewed with consternation by trade economists, but is necessary to overcome critical objections to the adoption of an effective regime. Negotiating a Kyoto successor with these features would represent an important next step toward the larger objective of bringing all nations under the discipline of a meaningful international climate agreement.
"A Proposal for the Design of the Successor to the Kyoto Protocol" won the Harvard Project on International Climate Agreements open research paper competition.
Karp, Larry and Jinhua Zhao. “A Proposal for the Design of the Successor to the Kyoto Protocol.” Harvard Project on Climate Agreements, September 2008